Groundbreaking research that revolutionizes how we understand poverty - essential reading for anyone who cares about global development
The Reality of Extreme Poverty:
Try to imagine living in Miami or Modesto with 99 cents per day for almost all your everyday needs. In India, that would buy you fifteen small bananas or about 3 pounds of low-quality rice. Around the world in 2005, 865 million people lived on this amount. Yet what's striking is that even people who are this poor are just like the rest of us in almost every way - they have the same desires and weaknesses, are no less rational, and often put much careful thought into their choices because they have to be sophisticated economists just to survive.
Beyond the Big Questions:
Most poverty debates get fixated on "big questions" - What is the ultimate cause? How much faith in free markets? The battle lines are drawn between aid optimists like Jeffrey Sachs (who argued $195 billion could eliminate poverty) and aid pessimists like William Easterly and Dambisa Moyo (who argue aid does more harm than good). But Banerjee and Duflo argue this misses the point. Instead of discussing whether foreign aid works, we should focus on specific, solvable problems: How best to fight diarrhea? How to get children to attend school? These concrete problems have specific answers.
The Three I's - Ideology, Ignorance, and Inertia:
The authors identify three barriers that explain why policies fail: ideology (blind faith in markets or government), ignorance (lack of knowledge about what actually works), and inertia (failure to experiment and learn). The solution isn't choosing between left-wing or right-wing approaches, but rigorous testing of what actually helps the poor escape poverty. This requires randomized controlled trials - bringing the gold standard of medical research to development economics.
The Nutrition Puzzle:
If the poor were truly starving, they would spend every available penny on calories. But they don't. Food represents only 45-77% of consumption among the rural extremely poor. In Udaipur, typical poor households could spend 30% more on food if they cut expenditures on alcohol, tobacco, and festivals. When they do spend more on food, they don't maximize calories - they buy better-tasting, more expensive calories. The poor choose food not mainly for cheap prices and nutritional value, but for taste. This isn't irrationality - it's the human need for a pleasant life even in extreme poverty.
Health: Prevention vs. Cure Behavior:
The poor spend heavily on expensive cures rather than cheap prevention. In Udaipur, every third household was repaying a loan taken for health care at 42% annual interest. Yet simple preventions are extremely cost-effective: $100 spent on chlorine can prevent thirty-two cases of diarrhea; a $14 bed net lasting five years can generate $88 annual returns by preventing malaria. The issue isn't how much the poor spend on health, but what it's spent on. They shun free public health care for expensive private "doctors" - half of whom lack medical degrees.
The Learning Crisis in Education:
Getting children into school isn't enough if they learn nothing. In India, 35% of children aged 7-14 cannot read a simple paragraph, and 60% cannot read a simple story. Only 30% can do basic division - despite many helping parents with complex calculations in family businesses. Teachers miss one day of work out of five, and even when present, 50% aren't in front of a class when they should be. The tragedy is that simple interventions work: volunteer "balsakhis" with barely ten years of schooling plus a week's training generated twice the learning gains of private schooling.
The Psychology of Poverty:
The poor often resist programs designed to help them because they don't share our faith that these programs work. Parents see education as a lottery ticket rather than a safe investment - they overstate both upside and downside. They may send one "intelligent" child to school while calling others "stupid" to their faces. This creates a winner-take-all mentality that prevents investment in all children. The poor are also more present-focused, skeptical about radical change, and focus on living as pleasantly as possible today.
Family Planning Realities:
Pak Sudarno wanted nine children not from lack of family planning knowledge, but because he needed insurance for old age. Large families are often rational responses to uncertainty and lack of social safety nets. The most effective population policy might be making it unnecessary to have so many children through health insurance, old age pensions, or financial development that enables profitable retirement savings. When women gain bargaining power (like having their names on property titles), fertility declines significantly.
Risk and Insurance:
The poor are like hedge-fund managers - they live with huge amounts of risk, except they're liable for 100% of losses and must raise all capital themselves. Agricultural wages in Bangladesh can vary 18% above or below average in normal years. The poor cope through diversification: families have multiple occupations, multiple plots in different areas, and temporary migration. But informal insurance networks provide imperfect protection, especially for health shocks. Formal insurance faces moral hazard, adverse selection, and fraud challenges.
Credit Market Failures:
Less than 7% of rural poor have bank loans. They borrow from informal sources at 40-200% annual interest rates - rates that would make U.S. savers rich if they could earn them. This paradox exists because lending to the poor involves high transaction costs, limited enforcement, and political interference. Government credit programs historically achieved 40% default rates. The poor need credit not just for investment but for consumption smoothing during inevitable income fluctuations.
The Power of Randomized Experiments:
The book's revolutionary contribution is showing how randomized controlled trials can answer development questions definitively. Instead of arguing about whether bed nets should be free or sold, researchers tested both approaches and found free distribution works better. Instead of debating conditional vs. unconditional cash transfers, experiments showed both work equally well for education. This evidence-based approach moves beyond ideology to discover what actually works.
Time Inconsistency and Nudges:
People think about the present differently from the future. Small costs that must be endured now feel much more unpleasant than when planning for the future. This explains why immunization rates increased sevenfold when families received dal (dried beans) for each shot. The incentive didn't change minds about immunization's value - it overcame present-bias that made parents postpone taking action they already believed was good.
Why This Book Matters:
Banerjee and Duflo (both Nobel Prize winners) demonstrate that fighting poverty requires understanding the poor as sophisticated decision-makers facing impossible trade-offs, not as passive victims needing rescue. Their randomized trials methodology has transformed development economics, proving that rigorous testing can identify interventions that dramatically improve lives at low cost. The book offers hope - not through grand theories, but through accumulating evidence about specific, solvable problems.
This isn't just academic research - it's practical wisdom for anyone working in development, social entrepreneurship, or policy. The insights about human psychology, decision-making under extreme constraints, and designing effective interventions apply far beyond poverty. Every page challenges assumptions and provides tools for evidence-based problem-solving.
Click here to see it on Amazon
Ease to Read
Insights
My Love-Indicator
<Back